• ISSN:2971-7930 (E) == ISSN:0189-0662 (Print)
CNAJ - CAPITALIZATION OF HUMAN CAPITAL ACQUISITION & DEVELOPMENT COST AND RETURN ON EQUITY OF LISTED MANUFACTURING COMPANIES IN NIGERIA

CAPITALIZATION OF HUMAN CAPITAL ACQUISITION & DEVELOPMENT COST AND RETURN ON EQUITY OF LISTED MANUFACTURING COMPANIES IN NIGERIA

Home CAPITALIZATION OF HUMAN CAPITAL ACQUISITION & DEVELOPMENT COST AND RETURN ON EQUITY OF LISTED MANUFACTURING COMPANIES IN NIGERIA

Authors

Josephine Adanma Nmesirionye,

Abstract

The modern day accounting practice raised an issue in the area of not recognizing human capital as an asset and because the human capital is not recognized as an asset, it is omitted in the statement of financial position as an intangible asset. This study examined the effect of capitalizing human capital acquisition & development cost on Return on Equity. Using ex-post facto research design, eight listed manufacturing firms were purposively selected from the listed manufacturing firms across four sectors which engage in consumer goods, industrial, basic materials and oil and gas. The study adopted a panel regression method in analyzing the data collected from the annual reports of the firm from 2013- 2020. Finding from the study revealed that human capital acquisition & development cost have a significant effect on Return on Equity of listed Manufacturing Companies in Nigeria. Based on the finding, the study recommends that Regulators should set up a strong accounting policy geared towards ensuring that human capital acquisition & development cost are treated as capital expenditure. This practice will enhance the performance of firms (ROE).

Full Text

1.0       Introduction

Resources are key drivers for every business success, the need for these adequate resources (in the form of financial, physical and intangible assets) in ensuring the continuous operation of a business as a going concern can never be looked down on. These resources range from physical assets, financial and other intangible assets, all needed for the growth of a company. Before the millennium, there was a growing prediction that less people will do physical work and more people will do brain work, this is “intellectual capital”, and it doesn’t appear on the company statement of financial performance, but reflects more value for organizations than that of physical assets.

A capital is a Wealth in the form of money or assets that shows the financial strength of an individual, organization, or nation, and assumed to be available for development or investment. It is money invested in a business to generate income. In economics, it is the factors of production that are used to create goods or services and are not themselves in the process (BusinessDictionary.com). The modern day business has changed what constitutes a capital of an organization. There is no doubt that companies need strong and competitive human resource to succeed; the success of firms whether large, medium or small, depends on the quality and value of human resource they have. According to Robbins (2001), a major feature that differentiates successful organizations from their contemporaries in almost all economic sectors is the quality of the people they are able to get and retain. Knowledge has, indeed, become power and organizations in our ever changing world consider knowledge and intellect of their employees as a competitive edge to compete effectively in the market place (Kharal, Zai-ur-Rehman, Abrar & Khan 2014). Therefore, money spent on employee’s training and development is generally viewed as one of the critical investments that companies could make, and that such investments should be treated as a capital expenditure.

A key contributory factor to organizational performance is the human resource of an organization (Nmesirionye, Okezie, Enobong & Udoayang, 2021).  It relates to the totality of an organization's resources not expressly reflected in financial statements but creates value, defines it's competencies and distinguishes the organization to have competitive advantage (Jones, Onuche & Nmesirionye, 2019).

Despite the advent of information technology which has made the whole world to become a global village, human intellect is still the brain behind business success. There is no technological or service base evolution, however sound it may be, that has not and will not be driven by human intellect which is the ability, knowledge and skill of such an individual. For companies to seek new ways of developing and maintaining competitive advantage in the present dynamic environment, it is important that firms truly leverage on their workforce as a competitive weapon. To leverage on the workforce means an improvement largely on the procurement of the right people with high level of intellectual competence, hence the need for expenditure on human capital. Basically, the concept of human capital cost arose from the transformation of individual competence into highly productive human capital with the effective input of education, health and moral value. It is one of the biggest asset of an organization (Nmesirionye, Egwu, Okoro & Obizuo, 2021).

This present century is knowledge driven, it is therefore necessary for organizations to utilize its human capital in such a way that will not make it’s success to be at stake. This can be achieved by ensuring that the human capital that will drive the economy be recognized as a valuable part of the total value of an organization in order to assess the effect it has on the overall performance of an organization. Against this back-drop, this study seeks to evaluate the effect of capitalizing human capital acquisition & development cost on return on equity of listed manufacturing companies in Nigeria.

1.1       Statement of Problem

The modern day accounting practice raised an issue in the area of not recognizing human capital as an asset and because the human capital is not recognized as an asset, it is omitted in the statement of financial position as an intangible asset. This dilemma restricted many organizations from investing in the human resource on the ground that any expense in this direction will reduce the organization's profit; instead, huge resources are spent on non-human asset to the detriment of the human resource that coordinates the other factors in an organization.

Capitalizing human capital; that is, recognizing human capital as an intangible asset will change the perception of owners of business entities towards their human resource. This will create more avenues for investment in this area since; the employer knows from the onset that he is going to recoup the fund invested. More investment on human resource in terms of training and retraining will have a corresponding positive effect on technical-know-how of the human resource but the problem remains, “to what extent does the capitalization of human resource cost (acquisition and development cost) affect Return on Equity?" This study seeks to proffer solution to this problem at the end.

1.2       Objective of the study           

The objective of this study is to examine the effect of capitalizing human capital acquisition & development cost on Return on Equity of listed Manufacturing Companies in Nigeria.

1.3       Research Question

To what extent does capitalizing human capital acquisition & development cost affect Return on Equity of listed Manufacturing Companies in Nigeria?

1.4       Research Hypothesis

H0: Human capital acquisition & development cost have no significant effect on Return on Equity of listed Manufacturing Companies in Nigeria.

2.0       Review of Related Literature

2.1       Conceptual Framework

2.1.1    Human capital

According to Nmesirionye,  et al (2021).  Human capital refers to a set of individuals who make up the workforce of an organization or a business entity.  It relates to the totality of an organization's resources not expressly reflected in financial statements but creates value, defines its competencies and distinguishes that organization to have competitive advantage (Jones et al., 2019). The development of human capital involves training and retraining of human resource and usually cost driven.

Training is a learning process that aims to permanently improve the ability and behavior of the employees by enabling them to acquire new skill, knowledge and attitude for more efficient performance. Which includes: identification of training needs; developing suitable training programmes; providing requisite job skills and knowledge to employees; evaluating the effectiveness of training programmes? Training is considered fundamentally important to human capital development. It could be described as the vehicle that takes organization to their destination within a stipulated time frame. Development is the growth or realization of a person‘s ability, through conscious or unconscious learning. Development programs usually include phases of planned study and experience, and are usually supported by a coaching or counseling facility. Development occurs when a gain in experience is effectively combined with the conceptual understanding that can illustrate it, giving increased confidence both to act and to perceive how such action relates to its context (Bolton, 2017).

According to Becker (2018), there are three types of training or knowledge, which are directly related to rate of return and human capital. Becker specified these trainings or knowledge as investments in human capital. These three types of training or knowledge according to him are: on-the-job training - learning new skills and perfecting old ones while on the job. Broken down into two types of training; general training- those skills which are useful in many firms besides those providing it; specific training - training that has no effect on the productivity of trainees that would be useful in other firms; schooling - an institution specializing in the production of training, as distinct from a firm that offers training in conjunction with the production of goods; and knowledge - any other information which a person obtains to increase their command of their economic situation. On-the-job training is intended to improve old skills and provide new skills while employed by a firm. These skills are either transferable or specific. On-the-job training is provided by a firm and utilized to increase the outputs of the firm and to increase the income of the individual. This type of training is valued through the time and effort of the trainees, the teaching provided by others, and the equipment and materials used. These are costs that are incurred from reducing current production in order to increase future production (Armstrong, 2017). On-the-training time periods can vary greatly as more time is spent on an intern than a machine operator (Becker, 2018). General training provides transferable skills to the worker. These types of skills are rarely costly to the firm - most of the trainees bare the cost of general training and reap the benefits of the returns. Employees pay for the general on-the-job training by receiving wages below what they could receive elsewhere. For example, a machinist trained in the military receives lower wages than we would in the competitive labour market; however he finds his skill has value in steel or aircraft firms, and a doctor in residency at one hospital finds his skills are highly transferable to other hospitals or private practice in the future. Most general on-the-job training presumably increases the future marginal productivity of the workers in the firm providing the training and in other firms (Barney, 2018). Specific training refers to training provided by a firm that has limited transferability and only increases productivity within the contextual setting. For example, when a firm hires new employees - most times, they are orientated to the culture, specific policies and procedures, and other processes to familiarize the new employees with their organization. This type of training is specific because the knowledge acquired raises productivity in the firm providing the knowledge than in other firms. Some specific training may not be useful in a single firm or in most firms, but in a set of firms defined by a product, type of work, or geographical location (Coleman, 2017). School training (schooling) is completed off the job and at an institution that specializes in either one skill or multiple skills. Schools are often substitutions for on-the job training at a firm. This is evidence by the shift in training programs from the firm to the school such as legal apprenticeships to law school, and on-the-job engineering experience to engineering schools (Becker, 2018). Most training programs develop on-the-job than transfer to formal institutions because industry usually sees the value of the training much before schools. Most schooling costs are absorbed by the student in order to reap the benefits of the returns later from higher wages from specialized skill sets. Training of employees results in increased productivity in any organization. The technological growth of any nation depends on the bulk of trained human resources available.  Kennedy, as reported by Gary (2017), once said that manpower is the basic resource, the indispensable means of correcting other resources to mankind's use and benefit. How well we train, develop, and employ the human skill is fundamental in deciding how we will accomplish as organizations. The manner in which we do this will profoundly depend on the kind of nation we have.

According to Armstrong (2017), workers have the ability to acquire ―other knowledge from many sources. Other knowledge has the same ability to increase worker wages as on-the-job training, specific and general training, as well as schooling. Information about the prices charged by different sellers would enable a person to buy from the cheapest, thereby raising his command over resources; information about the wages offered by different firms would enable him to work for the firm paying the highest wage. Becker (2018) claimed that one of the most influential theoretical concepts in human capital analysis is the distinction between general and specific training or knowledge. The distinction helps explain why workers with highly specific skills are less likely to quit their jobs and are the last to be laid off during business downturns. It also explains why most promotions are made from within a firm rather than through hiring (Barney, 2018). Becker has established the rationale for firms to provide highly specific training to their workers. This type of training reaps benefits for the firm through higher productivity and for the worker through higher wages.

The distribution of responsibilities is suggested to lead to specialization. However, to be able to utilize their specialization in the best possible way, the work-tasks should be rotated among the employees so as to broaden their field of specialization as well as their knowledge about the organization's operation as a whole. Therefore, once a year the work-tasks should be rotated among the various employees depending upon their qualifications and suitability to perform the new work-task.

The tools and methods for human capital development differ in organizations, and it is largely determined by the objectives of organizations, the idiosyncrasy of management staff, the organizational policy, as well as the organizational environment.

2.1.2 Staff Costs

These are expenses incurred in the course of acquiring, training and retraining of the human elements in an organization; that generate economic output. It involves employee salary and other benefits. Employee benefits are part of an employee‘s total reward package provided along with his/her usual cash payments (Armstrong, 2016). It can be inform of medical insurance, and pension scheme, car allowance and season ticket loan; or benefits which are not strictly classified as remuneration: holiday trips. Benefits provided by employers are tax deductible, sometime regarded as benefits in kind, with the notable exception of some benefits including pension schemes, canteen meals, car parking, professional subscriptions and other benefits that are used mainly for job duties. Employee benefit play a significant role in employer-employee relationship and this has proven to be advantageous to both parties. Employees see their benefits to be as important as their basic salary. This is because most employee benefits enable employees to make savings, or provide amenities that otherwise would have been difficult to get. The benefits offer by employers to employees have been on the increasing rate, notwithstanding, the major problem is that most employers want to cut down costs and in most cases, do not understand what their employees want and so provide the wrong employee benefits.

2.1.3 Return on Equity (ROE)

Return on equity (ROE) is a measure of financial performance calculated by dividing net income after tax by shareholder's equity. Because shareholder's equity is equal to a company’s assets minus its debt, ROE could be thought of as the return on net assets (Newbold, Zumwalt & Kannan, 2017). ROE is considered a measure of how effectively management is using a company’s assets to create profits. Return on Equity (ROE) ratio measures firm’s profitability by revealing how much profit a company generates with the money shareholders have invested. 

2.1.4 Measurement and Capitalization of Human Capital

Establishing the different dimensions of human resource costs, investments and the worth of employees (the value of human resource) and capitalizing is the major issue in Human Resource Accounting. Many methods and models for making this determination have evolved in literature. The first is the Discounted Wages Method (Lev & Schwartz, 1971), the Historical Acquisition Cost Method (Flamboltz, 1972), the Replacement Cost Method; regarded as the Adjusted (Present) Value Method (Hermansson, 1964), and the Goodwill Method (Pyle, 1970). These methods of capitalizing human resource costs fall into two main measurement approaches – The cost approach which involves methods based on the costs incurred by the organization on employees, and the economic value approach which includes methods based on the economic value of the human resources and their contributions to the company’s overall profit.

2.2       Theoretical Framework

This work is anchored on Human capital theory.

Human capital theory was developed by Schultz 1961.The origin of human capital goes back to emergence of classical economics in 1776 and thereafter it was developed as scientific theory. The idea of investing in human capital was first propounded by Adam (1963), who argued in the Wealth of Nations that differences between the ways of working of individuals with different levels of education and training reflected differences in the returns necessary to defray the costs of acquiring those skills. Economists such as Elliot (1991) developed the theory of human capital. He is concerned with human capital in terms of the quality, not quantity, of the labour supply.

The theory has it that a person's formal education determines his or her earning power. Human capital theory holds that it is the key competences, skills, knowledge and abilities of the workforce that contributes to organisation’s competitive advantage. It focuses attention on resourcing, human resource development, and reward strategies and practices. According to Human Capital Theory, education is an investment because it is believed that it could potentially bestow private and social benefits. Human capital theorists believe that education and earning power are correlated, which means, theoretically, that the more education one has, the more one can earn, and that the skills, knowledge and abilities that education provides can be transferred into the work in terms of productivity, (Dae-bong, 2009).

Human capital theory recognized that not all employees possess the knowledge and skills that are of equal importance. It should be remembered that no two individuals are exactly alike. This theory drew attention on the resource based view of the firm, human capital theory, and transaction cause economics to develop human resource architecture of four different employment modes: internal development, acquisition of knowledge and skill, contracting of one another, alliance between workers. This theory implies that growth in human capital has a lot of implications on economic growth as such any country that neglects human capital development, directly or indirectly neglects its economic growth indices. Human capital theory further postulates that education and earning power have direct relationship; which implies that an increase in education will result to an increase in earning. Similarly, the theory emphasized that the skill, knowledge and abilities provided by education can be transferred into work in terms of enhanced productivity. The link between this theory and the present study is that the present study tries to find out how capitalizing human capital cost affects return on equity; The theory directs the a priori expectation of the present study.

2.3       Empirical Review

Allam (2018) examined intellectual capital and firm performance; differentiating between accounting based and market based performance and studied 198 firms for two gulf cooperation council countries; Kingdom of Saudi Arabia and Kingdom of Bahrain for the period 2014 - 2016. The value added intellectual coefficient model was adopted along with two performance measures: accounting based represented by return on assets and market based performance proxied by Tobin's Q. The paper adopted panel regression method of data estimation and found that there is positive relationship between intellectual capital and return on asset while there is negative association between intellectual capital and Tobin Q.

Onyekwelu, Okoh and Iyidiobi (2017) studied effect of intellectual capital on financial performance of banks in Nigeria and adopted ex post facto research design. It used value added intellectual coefficient to determine the effect of intellectual capital indices on financial performance. Secondary data were collected from 3 banks annual reports using regression analysis to estimate the data. They established that human capital efficiency has a positive and significant effect on banks financial performance but capital employed efficiency and structural capital efficiency are not significant and further indicated that the banks with high intellectual capital also showed high financial performance. The study recommended that banks should improve on their human capital as findings showed that it has impact on their financial performance.

Ali (2015) investigated effect of intellectual capital components on financial performance of deposit money banks in Nigeria from 2006 to 2013. Secondary data was employed engaging purposively sampling eight banks from the total population of banks listed on the Nigeria Stock Exchange. The paper used human capital efficiency, structural capital efficiency and capital employed efficiency as the intellectual components and adopted correlation and multi-linear regression techniques to analyze the data collected. The study revealed the intellectual capital components have positive and significant effect on the financial performance of deposit money banks in Nigeria. The study therefore recommended that money deposit banks should enhance capacity through staff training and development and setting of clear performance standards.

Adebawojo, Enyi and Adebawo (2015) investigated the likely effect of human asset accounting on the performance of business organizations in Nigeria. The empirical study adopted an Ex-post facto research design, conducted on all 18 publicly quoted banks in Nigeria capital market. The instrument of data collection was questionnaire designed on a six steps Likert Scale and validated through peer review with Cronbach Alpha Coefficient of 0.807 and 0.870 for Human Asset and Organisation Performance respectively. The hypothesis was tested using simple regression model. The result of the analyses confirmed that human asset accounting significantly affects the banks’ performance at F-ratio = 56.280, P≤ 0.05, R2 =0.193. It concluded that capitalizing human assets would positively impact on performance of organizations and recommended its disclosure as intangible asset in the balance sheet.

3.0       Methodology

3.1       Research Design

This study adopted ex-post facto research design. The choice for this design is because the study attempted to explore cause and effect relationship between human capital acquisition & development cost and Return on Equity using existing micro-economic data.

3.2       Method of Data Collection

The study extracted secondary data from annual financial report of eight listed manufacturing companies in Nigeria from 2013 - 2020. The period of 2013 - 2020 was selected because some of the firms were listed nine (9) years ago and their published financial statements that can be obtained is for a period of eight (8) years.

The sampling technique adopted is judgmental. The listed manufacturing firms were grouped into 4 sectors by the Nigerian Stock Exchange vis-a-vis consumer goods, industrial, basic material and oil and gas. Based on the grouping, two (2) firms from each sector were selected on the basis of those that report their human capital acquisition and development cost in their financial statement. See appendix.

3.3       Explanation of Variables

The dependent variable Return On Equity (ROE) was obtain after the human capital acquisition & development cost have been yearly capitalized and amortized at 15years using a straight-line method. It was based on the IAS 38 on intangibles. See appendix.

 

 

 

3.4       Method of Data Estimation

The study employed balanced panel data based simple regression model in view of the longitudinal data structure. Fixed effect, random effect and diagnostic houseman test was conducted. Housman test helps in selection of the regression between fixed and random effect taking into consideration the chi-square probability value. The fixed effect therefore is favoured if houseman test result is significant at 5% otherwise, the random effect is preferred. The OLS which is the best linear unbiased estimator was used to test the hypothesis.

3.5       Specification of Model

The model specification is as follows;

ROE = (HCA & DC )

Where;

ROE = Return On Equity

HCA & DC = Human Capital Acquisition & Development Cost

The above model is presented in econometric form

ROE  = β0 + β1 HCA & DCit  + eit

Where;

β0 =       constant intercept term

β1 =       slope coefficient

i   =       cross section of companies

t  =      time period of data

 

4.0       Result and Discussion

4.1       Stationarity/ Unit Root Tests

Table 1. Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) Test

Variables

ADF Stat

P-value

Level form

ACQ. & DEV. Cost

30.4625

0.0157

1st difference

ROE

24.9571

0.0406

1st  difference

Source: E-view Computation

 

To avoid running a spurious regression, a unit root test was carried out to ensure that the variables employed in this study are mean reverting i.e stationary. For this purpose the Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) test was utilized and the result of the test as presented in table 1 shows that acquisition & development cost and Return on Equity are stationary at first difference. This is because ADF t-statistic in absolute term has P-value less than  0.05 level of significance. This result therefore confirms the stationarity of variables used in the analysis.

 

Table 2: Cointegration Test result for the hypothesis

Pedroni Residual Cointegration Test

 

 

Series: ROE ACQ____DEV__COST

 

 

Date: 11/18/21   Time: 19:09

 

 

Sample: 2013 2020

 

 

 

Included observations: 64

 

 

Cross-sections included: 8

 

 

Null Hypothesis: No cointegration

 

 

Trend assumption: Deterministic intercept and trend

 

User-specified lag length: 1

 

 

Newey-West automatic bandwidth selection and Bartlett kernel

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Alternative hypothesis: common AR coefs. (within-dimension)

 

 

 

 

Weighted

 

 

 

Statistic

Prob.

Statistic

Prob.

Panel v-Statistic

 5.672677

 0.0000

 1.991055

 0.0232

Panel rho-Statistic

-0.372740

 0.3547

 0.969658

 0.8339

Panel PP-Statistic

-8.331693

 0.0000

-5.120370

 0.0000

Panel ADF-Statistic

-0.174024

 0.4309

-2.262844

 0.0118

 

 

 

 

 

 

Since the probability value of ADF-statistics of 0.4309 is greater than 0.05, it implies that there is no long run relationship between acquisition & development cost and return on equity.

Table 3: Hausman Test

Correlated Random Effects - Hausman Test

 

Equation: Untitled

 

 

Test cross-section random effects

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Test Summary

Chi-Sq. Statistic

Chi-Sq. d.f.

Prob.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cross-section random

0.215730

1

0.6423

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cross-section random effects test comparisons:

 

 

 

 

 

Variable

Fixed 

Random

Var(Diff.)

Prob.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ACQ____DEV__COST

0.109581

0.070715

0.007002

0.6423

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Table 3 shows the Hausman test result conducted to choose between fixed effects model and random effects model in panel data. Based on the result, random effect panel data is preferable. This is so because the null hypothesis was accepted based on the decision rule given that P-value of 0.6463 is greater than 0.05

Table 4 Panel Data Regression Analysis (Random Effect Test)

Dependent Variable: ROE

 

 

Method: Panel EGLS (Cross-section random effects)

Date: 11/18/21   Time: 19:12

 

 

Sample: 2013 2020

 

 

Periods included: 8

 

 

Cross-sections included: 8

 

 

Total panel (balanced) observations: 64

 

Swamy and Arora estimator of component variances

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Variable

Coefficient

Std. Error

t-Statistic

Prob. 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

C

-0.366657

0.080650

-4.546278

0.0000

ACQ____DEV__COST

0.070715

0.011468

6.166300

0.0000

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Effects Specification

 

 

 

 

 

S.D. 

Rho 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Cross-section random

0.013318

0.0249

Idiosyncratic random

0.083420

0.9751

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Weighted Statistics

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

R-squared

0.383148

    Mean dependent var

0.114493

Adjusted R-squared

0.373199

    S.D. dependent var

0.104698

S.E. of regression

0.082890

    Sum squared resid

0.425991

F-statistic

38.51039

    Durbin-Watson stat

0.532850

Prob(F-statistic)

0.000000

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Unweighted Statistics

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

R-squared

0.421405

    Mean dependent var

0.125625

Sum squared resid

0.434510

    Durbin-Watson stat

0.522402

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

SOURCE: E-VIEW COMPUTATION

The panel data result shows the effect of human capital acquisition & development cost on return on equity of listed manufacturing companies in Nigeria.

The coefficient of determination R-square of 0.383 implied that 38.3% of the sample variation in the dependent variable return on equity (ROE) is explained or caused by the explanatory variable (human capital acquisition and development cost) while 61.7% is unexplained. This remaining 61.7% could be caused by other factors or variables not built into the model. Consequently, the value of the adjusted R2 is 0.373. This shows that the regression line which captures 37.3 per cent of the total variation in ROE is caused by variation in the explanatory variable specified in the model with 62.7 per cent accounted for the stochastic error term. The F-statistic was also used to test the overall significant of the model. The F-value of 38.51039 with P-value of 0.0000 is an indication that the model is statistically significant at 5 percent level of significant. Finally, the test of autocorrelation using Durbin-watson shows that the Durbin-watson value of 0.532850 falls outside the conclusive region of Durbin-watson partition curve. Hence, we can clearly say that there is no sign of autocorrelation.

4.2       Test of Hypothesis

H0: Human capital acquisition & development cost have no significant effect on return on equity of listed manufacturing companies in Nigeria.

HA: Human capital acquisition & development cost have significant effect on return on equity of listed manufacturing companies in Nigeria.

 

The F-statistic with 38.51039 has probability of 0.0000 level of significance. Since the probability of the F statistics is less than 5% level of significance, we reject the null hypothesis, and therefore conclude that human capital acquisition & development cost have a significant effect on return on equity of listed manufacturing companies in Nigeria.

 

4.3       Discussions of Finding

Finding from this study showed that human capital acquisition & development cost have a significant effect on return on equity of listed manufacturing companies in Nigeria. This is evident from the result of the analysis where F-ratio = 38.51039 with P-value of 0.0000 which is less than 5 percent. However, this finding is in line with that of Adebawojo, et-al which revealed that capitalizing human assets would positively impact on the performance of organizations.

5.0       Conclusion and Recommendation

5.1       Conclusion

The study evaluated the effect of capitalizing human capital acquisition & development cost on return on equity. Indeed, the practice of treating human capital acquisition & development cost as an expense and charged against the current periods should be discouraged. The money spent on acquiring and developing employees should be considered as one of the critical investments any firm could make and as such, should be treated as a capital expenditure. This study was carried out using eight selected manufacturing firms listed in Nigerian Stock Exchange.  Human capital acquisition & development cost was capitalized and used  as proxy for independent variables while Return on Equity was used as proxy for dependent variable. The finding revealed that human capital acquisition & development cost when capitalized has a significant effect on Return on Equity. The study therefore concludes that capitalizing human capital acquisition & development cost has significant effect on Return on Equity of Manufacturing firms in Nigeria.

5.2       Recommendation

In consonance with this study’s findings, it became imperative to recommend that Regulators should set up a strong Accounting policy geared towards ensuring that human capital acquisition & development cost are treated as capital expenditure. This practice will enhance the performance of firms vis avis. Return on Equity.

 

 

 

REFERENCES

Adebawojo, O. A; Enyi, P. E and Adebawo O. O. (2015). Human asset accounting and corporate performance. American International Journal of Contemporary Research 5(1), 42-54.

Ali, U. L (2015). Effect of intellectual capital of corporate valuation of oil and gas firms in Nigeria. Research Journal of Sustainability Accounting and Reporting 4(7), 50-59.

Allam, P. H, (2018) Intellectual capital and financial returns of company. Journal of intellectual capital, 8(1) 76-95.

Armstrong, M. (2016). How Intellectual Capital Affects a Firm’s Performance. Austrian Journal of Business and Management Research 2(8), 24-31.

Armstrong, M. (2017). Strategic human resource management: A handbook of human resource management practice, 10th ed. London: Kogan Page.

Barney J. (2018). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17(4), 99–120.

Becker, G.S. (2018). Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education (3rd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Bolton, M. (2017). Assessment and development in Europe: Adding value to individuals and organization, Maidenhead: McGraw Hill.

Coleman , J. S (2017).  Social capital in the creation of human capital, American Journal of Sociology 94 (1988), 95-120.

Dae-bong, K. (2009). Human capital and its measurement, the 3rd OECD World Forum on Statistics, Knowledge and Policy, Charting progress, Building Visions, Improving life. Korea: Busan.

Flamholtz, E. G. (1972). Toward a Theory of Human Resoure Value in Formal Organizations. The Accounting Review, October, 666-678.

 

Gary R.S. (2017). Hands-On Training: A Simple and Effective Method for On-the-Job Training. Colorado: Berrett-Koehler Publishers Retrieved from: www.bkconnection.com.

Hermansson, R. (1964). Accounting for Human Assets. Occasional Paper No. 14, Michigan State University.

 

Jones, E., Onuche, S.E.V. and Nmesirionye, J.A (2019). Empirical investigation of intellectual capital and return on assets of listed commercial banks on Nigeria stock exchange: Comparative analysis of banks. European Journal of Accounting, Finance and Investment 5(2), 3466-7037.

Kharal, M.; Zai-ur-Rehman, M.; Abrar, M.; & Khan, M.S. (2014). Intellectual Capital and Firm Performance: An Empirical Study on the Oil and Gas Sector of Pakistan. International Journal of Accounting and Financial Reporting 4(1).

 

Lev, B. & Schwartz, A. (1971). On the Use of the Economic Concept of Human Capital in Financial Statements. The Accounting Review, January, 103 – 112.

 

 

Nmesirionye, J.A, Okezie, O.K, Enobong, E.U & Udoayang,J.O (2021). Effect of Employee Cost on Financial performance of Banks in Nigeria. Journal of Association of National Accountants of Nigeria, 29(4), 27-34.

 

Nmesirionye, J.A, Egwu, O.L, Okoro, C.C, & Obizuo C.J ( 2021). Human Resource Accounting and Profitability of Commercial Banks In Nigeria.4th International Conference on Managing Nigerian's Economy in the Digitalized Covid 19, 414-424

 

Newbold, P., Zumwalt, J.K. and Kannan, S. (2017). Combining forecasts to improve earnings per share predicition: An examination of electric utilities. International Journal of Forecast 3(8), 229-238.

Onyekwelu, U. L. F., Osisioma, B. C., & Ugwuanyi, U.B, (2015), Impact of  human accounting on corporate financial performance- A study of selected banks in Nigeria, European Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance Research, 3(5), 90-107.

 

Pyle, W. C. (1970). Human Resource Accounting. Financial Analysts Journal, September-October, 69-78.

 

Robbins S.P. (2001), Organizational behavior - concepts, controversies and applications. 4th edition. Englewood Cliffs; New Jersey: Prentice Hall International.

 

 

 

 

 

 

Appendix (Authors Compilation)

 

Yr

Firms

*A

A&D Cost (Yearly)

**B

Amortization (Per period)

B=A/15

*C

Equity(BC)

D

Equity(AC)

D=C+I

*E

PAT(BC)

**F

PAT(AC)

F=E+A-H

**G

Equity  Ratio (AC)

G=F/D

**H

Accum. Amortization

H=SUM OF B

I

Additional profit/loss

I=A-H

LOG = A&D COST

2013

BOC GAS

12852000

856800

886215537

898210737

158664840

170660040

0.19

856800

11995200

7.10897071

2014

BOC GAS

15145000

1009667

941634173

954912706

149056627

162335160

0.17

1866467

13278533

7.18026927

2015

BOC GAS

15361000

1024067

924078534

936549000

118646394

131116860

0.14

2890534

12470466

7.18641948

2016

BOC GAS

20993000

1399533

1004986885

1021689818

95862947

112385880

0.11

4290067

16702933

7.32207450

2017

BOC GAS

2710000

144667

1007647734

1005923000

62080114

60355380

0.06

4434734

(1724734)

6.43296929

2018

BOC GAS

9541000

636067

932079101

936549000

32992061

37461960

0.04

5071101

4469899

6.97959389

2019

BOC GAS

7643000

509533

1038547634

1040610000

29155934

31218300

0.03

5580634

2062366

6.88326385

2020

BOC GAS

8219000

547933

899771567

901862000

24965427

27055860

0.03

6128567

2090433

6.91481898

2013

LAFERAGE

9865000

657667

5993992667

6003200000

119142667

1200640000

0.20

657667

9207333

6.99409708

2014

LAFERAGE

9042000

602800

7950202911

7951984444

1423575667

1431357200

0.18

7260467

1781533

6.95626450

2015

LAFERAGE

7218000

481200

74494231

79970564

1521182387

1519440720

0.19

1741667

5476333

6.85841687

2016

LAFERAGE

6634000

442267

12192559934

12197010000

1953705534

1951521600

0.16

2183934

4450066

6.82177546

2017

LAFERAGE

6045000

403000

12557188791

12560646857

1755032494

1758490560

0.14

2586934

3458066

6.78139630

2018

LAFERAGE

5321000

354733

23652429758

23654809091

2599649667

2602029000

0.11

2941667

2379333

6.72599325

2019

LAFERAGE

5002000

333467

52796055467

52797782333

4750073544

4751800410

0.09

3275134

1726866

6.69914368

2020

LAFERAGE

5142000

342800

54362294184

54363818250

4347581394

4349105460

0.08

3617934

1524066

6.71113207

2013

BERGER PAINT

12531000

835400

1176582800

1188278400

166546160

178241760

0.15

835400

11695600

7.09798572

2014

BERGER PAINT

16482000

1098800

1144748200

1159296000

112974760

127522560

0.11

1934200

14547800

7.21700990

2015

BERGER PAINT

11517000

767800

1251919400

1260734400

117258440

126073440

0.10

2702000

8815000

7.06133936

2016

BERGER PAINT

9365000

624333

1225713333

1231752000

67866453

73905120

0.06

3326333

6038667

6.97150778

2017

BERGER PAINT

1025000

601667

1273669769

1270766769

160122680

165199680

0.13

3928000

(2903000)

6.01072386

2018

BERGER PAINT

8145000

543000

1316635333

1320309333

115153840

118827840

0.09

4471000

3674000

6.91089108

2019

BERGER PAINT

7482000

498800

1366101133

1368613333

120663000

123175200

0.09

4969800

2512200

6.87401770

2020

BERGER PAINT

6532000

435467

143785267

144912000

14813587

15940320

0.11

5405267

1126733

6.81504617

2013

NIG. BREW.

9371452000

91430133

15347251518

24627273385

17846964273

19209273240

0.78

91430133

9280021867

9.97180688

2014

NIG. BREW

1944958000

129663867

44666869073

46390733073

17296336560

19020200560

0.41

221094000

1723864000

9.28891022

2015

NIG. BREW

2109478000

140631867

57727247867

59475000000

20852747867

22600500000

0.38

361725867

1747752133

9.32417500

2016

NIG. BREW

2235681000

149045400

87408290267

89133200000

20558390267

22283300000

0.25

510771267

1724909733

9.34940983

2017

NIG. BREW

2086547000

139103133

86155872855

87592545455

17833687400

19270360000

0.22

649874400

1436672600

9.31942817

2018

NIG. BREW

1978372000

131891467

82996570338

84193176471

13116233867

14312840000

0.17

781765867

1196606133

9.29630795

2019

NIG. BREW

2233463000

148897533

85811516189

87114315789

15248920400

16551720000

0.19

930663400

1302799600

9.34897876

2020

NIG. BREW

1573073000

104871533

80421961933

80959500000

9177601933

9715140000

0.12

1035534933

537538067

0.97076417

2013

DANGOTE FLOUR

10256000

683733

15684872177

15694444444

2815427733

2825000000

0.18

683733

9572267

7.01097801

2014

DANGOTE FLOUR

10045000

669667

14366308400

14375000000

2291308400

2300000000

0.16

1353400

8691600

7.00194994

2015

DANGOTE FLOUR

7965000

531000

20448464855

20454545455

2243919400

2250000000

0.11

1884400

6080600

6.90118578

2016

DANGOTE FLOUR

8654000

576933

22493807333

22500000000

2018807333

2025000000

0.09

2461333

6192667

6.93721689

2017

DANGOTE FLOUR

11025000

735000

18563599904

18571428571

2592171333

2600000000

0.14

3196333

7828667

7.04237859

2018

DANGOTE FLOUR

9786000

652400

23744062733

23750000000

1894062733

1900000000

0.08

3848733

5937267

6.99060521

2019

DANGOTE FLOUR

7324000

488267

18925584429

18928571429

1322013000

1325000000

0.07

4337000

2987000

6.86474833

2020

DANGOTE FLOUR

6589000

439267

27082020600

27083333333

1623687267

1625000000

0.06

5276267

1312733

6.81881950

2013

DANGOTE CEMENT

1106500

73767

65161113

66193846

7572467

8605200

0.13

73767

1032733

6.04395141

2014

DANGOTE CEMENT

1028900

65893

73237460

74124000

6528860

7412400

0.10

142360

886540

6.01237316

2015

DANGOTE CEMENT

1000800

66720

76834947

77626667

6194680

6986400

0.09

209080

791720

6.00034729

2016

DANGOTE CEMENT

794500

52966

63840879

64373333

5261146

5793600

0.09

262046

532454

5.90009390

2017

DANGOTE CEMENT

873200

58213

85864202

86417143

5496259

6049200

0.07

320259

552941

5.94111372

2018

DANGOTE CEMENT

705600

47040

87701699

88040000

4944099

5282400

0.06

367299

338301

5.84855857

2019

DANGOTE CEMENT

634800

42320

70369105

70594286

4716419

4941600

0.07

409619

225181

5.80263691

2020

DANGOTE CEMENT

586500

39100

90174219

90312000

4377819

4515600

0.05

448719

137781

5.76826801

2013

FORTE OIL

843000

56200

2920789867

2921576667

349802400

350589200

0.12

56200

786800

5.92582757

2014

FORTE OIL

932000

62133

2857836733

2858650400

285051373

285865040

0.10

118333

813667

5.96941591

2015

FORTE OIL

932000

62133

3720887666

3721639200

371412389

372163920

0.10

180466

751534

5.96941591

2016

FORTE OIL

721000

48067

4314451533

4314944000

387852493

388344960

0.09

228533

492467

5.85793526

2017

FORTE OIL

701000

46733

4545675980

4546101714

317801386

318227120

0.07

275266

425734

5.84571801

2018

FORTE OIL

632000

42133

4530376599

4530691200

226219959

226534560

0.05

317399

314601

5.80071707

2019

FORTE OIL

624000

41600

3343816599

3344081600

166939079

167204080

0.05

358999

265001

5.79518458

2020

FORTE OIL

598000

39864

3128135266

3128334400

156815568

156416720

0.05

398866

199134

5.77670118

2013

CAPITAL OIL

923000

61533

22843689993

22844551460

1141366106

1142227573

0.10

61533

861467

5.96520170

2014

CAPITAL OIL

910000

60667

10249372470

10250160270

1024288227

1025016027

0.10

122200

787800

5.95904139

2015

CAPITAL OIL

792000

52800

10738274711

10738891711

965883254

966500254

0.09

175000

617000

5.89872518

2016

CAPITAL OIL

702000

46800

9335033613

9335513813

746360905

746841105

0.08

221800

480200

5.84633711

2017

CAPITAL OIL

674000

44933

5539464950

5539872217

331985066

332392333

0.06

266733

407267

5.82865989

2018

CAPITAL OIL

608000

40553

3692947436

3693248150

221294175

221594889

0.06

307286

300714

5.78390357

2019

CAPITAL OIL

614000

40933

4847122419

4847388200

193629747

193895528

0.04

348219

265781

5.78816837

2020

CAPITAL OIL

586000

39067

3046731006

3046929720

152733772

152346486

0.05

387286

198714

5.76789761

Source: * Annual reports of the companies

                   **Authors’ compilation



Download PDF
Please wait...
Please wait...